The market power of big tech firms like Google, Apple, Facebook, Amazon, and Microsoft (the GAFAM) has long been a thorn in the eyes of the European Commission (EC).[1] Ever since the EU drafted the Digital Markets Act[2] to regulate market power in the digital markets, they faced strong protests.[3] The widely received Epic-Apple court decision in the US illustrates why regulation in digital markets is so complex and difficult. The ruling finds that there is competition between Apple’s App Store and Google’s Play Store, which fails to acknowledge the type of economic competition in the market. Instead of being competitive, Apple and Google create local monopolies because consumers are locked-in by monetary costs and by convenience. First, consumers are locked-in because they incur the monetary investment costs of having all choices. There cannot be competition between app stores when consumers can only choose the one app store that is tied to the phone. To have competition between app stores, consumers would need to purchase another phone, which is costly. Second, consumers are locked-in because of their convenience or “laziness”. Apple exploits this convenience by allowing the one-click purchase option only for their own payment system. To use the external payment, consumers must click several links, which is costly in terms of time and effort. The EU Digital Market Act will spur competition by eliminating lock-in effects from both monetary investment and from convenience. For instance, phone makers will be forced to allow all app stores and give equal treatment to external payment systems.
The Epic-Apple case.
The situation escalated when Fortnite was banned from Apple’s AppStore in August 2020. [4] Fortnite developer Epic Games was unwilling to pay the so-called “Apple Tax” of 30% which grants automatically one third of all profits coming from apps and in-app transactions to Apple. Epic, eager to reclaim the total ownership over its profits, tried to circumvent this “tax” by integrating a link into the game. The link recommends users to buy directly from Epic at a 20% discount using “VBucks” instead of Apple Pay. Apple then banned Epic from the AppStore because the implementation of the link violates Apple’s anti-steering clause that forbids developers to offer alternative payment systems in their apps.
Only a few hours after the ban, Epic Games filed a lawsuit against Apple’s abuse of market power.[5] Google followed Apple in throwing out Fortnite from its App store. But many companies, such as, AirBnB, and Facebook, publicly sided with Epic Games.[6] Spotify followed EpicGames in filing an antitrust complaint against Apple,[7] alleging that the “Apple Tax” harms consumer choice and stifles innovation.[8]
There are some big questions behind this case of Apple and Google against Epic Games and Spotify: Do Apple and Google create illegal monopolies with their app stores? Are Apple and Google abusing their in-app market power? Are consumers and users paying too much for apps and for items in these apps? Should we regulate the App stores of Apple and Google? Do we generally need more regulation to break up the GAFAM Tech Giants?
Epic win or Epic fail?
A widely received US court decision on the case Epic against Apple demonstrates how complex the regulation of big tech companies is. At first, the mixed ruling reads like a split decisions that favors both parties.[9] At second glance, we see that it fails to acknowledge Apple’s monopoly from lock-in effects.
On the one hand, Judge Yvonne Gonzalez Rogers states that “the Court cannot ultimately conclude that Apple is a monopolist and that the “AppStore is not in violation of antitrust law.” [10] This part of the ruling allows the iPhone maker to continue its prohibition of third-party app stores and in-app payment systems. It further implies that consumers who buy from the Apple App Store still must pay the Apple tax price of 30%.
On the other hand, Judge Rodgers decided that Apple partly engages in anticompetitive conduct by implementing its anti-steering clause that forces consumers to buy apps and in-app purchases directly from Apple’s app store. Trying to foster effective price competition, the ruling forces Apple to allow developers the integration of links into their apps that redirect users away from Apple’s in-app purchasing system towards alternative payment systems.
This seems like a fair ruling for Epic: It can integrate links into games that redirect consumers to a homepage of Epic where consumers can make in-app purchases at a price chosen by Epic. So why does Epic announce to appeal against the decision?[11] The following intuitive example shows why lock-in effects play an important role and shift market power to gatekeepers like Apple.
A simple illustrative example is enough to understand the AppStore’s Monopoly Power
Imagine a young couple named Eva and Jazz who live in the city “Appletown” where all buildings are owned by the powerful landlord named “Apple”. To print their wedding invitations, Eva and Jazz walk to the Apple Superstore, owned by the Apple landlord, to buy an Epic printer and some complementary ink cartridges. As there are no other stores in town, Eva and Jazz must buy the printer and all the cartridges at whatever price faced in the Apple Superstore.
Epic wants to enter the market and finds that it is profitable to run an Epic Superstore that allows selling printers and ink at prices that are 30% lower than the ones of the Apple Superstore.[12] However, despite many attempts Apple refuses to let Epic open a new store inside Apple town. Instead, the Apple landlord tells Epic that it can sell from outside the city walls, at a location 10kms away from the Apple Superstore. Consumers like Eva and Jazz face the following two options: (i) buying from Apple at a higher price or (ii) walk 10 kms to buy directly from Epic at a lower price.
Following a series of complaints against the Apple landlord and a court trial, a judge denies the opening of the Epic store in Appletown but forces the Apple Supermarket to inform Eva and Jazz about the alternative option to buy printers and ink outside town, at a possible lower price. This does not help our young couple. To enjoy the benefits of a lower price, Eva and Jazz still need to travel invest money and time to travel outside the city.
This is not a ruling that allows fair competition. Intuitively, a fair competitive environment includes competition between stores. To stay within the illustrative example, this means that Epic should be allowed to sell printers next to the Apple Superstore at a competitive price. Only the competitive pressure from stores side-by-side forces Apple to either reduce its markup and to improve its service in order to keep up with the competitor.
Lock-in Effects are a source of market power and can create local monopolies
It is easy to see that Eva and Jazz are the Fortnite players (or app users in general), who arrive at Apple’s store to purchase Epic’s apps (printers) and the complimentary in-app items (ink cartridges). Apple controls consumers’ access to the apps on the iPhone, which makes Apple a gatekeeper. The gatekeeper Apple has a local monopoly in the app- and in-app markets. The monopoly power stems from the fact that consumers are locked-in in two ways: by monetary costs and by habit or convenience. Both types of lock-in effects are internalized in the pricing decisions, which gives Apple market power to raise prices for the apps, and for items in these apps, well above the competitive level.
The first lock-in effect arises from the monetary investment costs of having all choices. Eva and Jazz, for instance, must invest money into transport to have free choice between two options. Similarly, Apple argues that they cannot have monopoly power given the free choice for consumers between several smartphone manufacturers, such as, HTC, Samsung, and Huawei. The fact of the matter is, iPhone users cannot choose between all the App Stores given that Apple offers only the AppStore on its phones. To have free choice between app stores, users would have to buy two or more phones, which is unrealistic for most consumers given the high smartphone costs of 500-1800 Euros.
The second type of lock-in effect stems from consumers’ convenience and their habits. Eva and Jazz might be busy with the wedding planning and prefer to pay a higher price in the local store instead of traveling outside the city walls. Lock-in from habit or convenience is the simple idea that once you purchase a good or service, you stick to it. This habit then makes it difficult for you to leave this company. The real-world analogue of consumers locked-in by their habits and convenience is being lead out of a game like Fortnite while playing it. The last thing that users want to do is to follow a link (or several) to register to a new payment system, purchase an item and then return to the game. This clearly reduces the gaming fun. The US court ruling, however, is agnostic about how Apple introduces the links that inform and direct users to alternative payment systems outside the apps.
Should we regulate the Big Tech?
The EU’s Digital Markets Act aims at making digital markets a fairer environment for consumers and app developers. It regulates the gatekeeper, that is, the one firm (Apple in our case) that controls access to final consumers and filtrates the access of other firms (Epic in our case). The upcoming Act addresses what the US court decision fails to address: lock-in effects that mainly benefit the GAFAM gatekeepers.
First, the Acts will require phone makers to allow the download of all app stores on each phone. This ingredient eliminates monetary investment costs and creates competition between app stores by letting consumers have all relevant choices on one phone. Second, the Act will reduce consumers’ convenience costs by giving equal and fair treatment to alternative payment systems. Now, consumers can make one-click purchases using Apple’s payment systems. When they want to use a different payment system, they are redirected out of the game to a different platform, which gives gatekeepers like Apple power to raise prices due to lock-in from convenience. The regulation would require Apple to allow Epic and others the integration of own one-click purchase buttons next to Apple’s payment system. This creates competition given that users can choose between equal payment systems.
This type of regulation is urgently needed because it ensures fair competition and protects consumers. It is easy to see how consumers would benefit from lower prices if Epic, for instance, introduces its own app store and payment system. Reducing market power of the gatekeepers Apple and Google would also allow consumers to have access to more products. Furthermore, competition for new and existing consumers puts pressure on companies to also offer more products of better quality. Apple, for instance, could respond to the new competition by introducing better features in the AppStore and find innovative ways to cut costs for maintaining the App Store’s quality control.
That is not to say that Apple’s and Google’s services are bad per-se. The Act that regulates market power from lock-in effects is more like the hand that removes the bad apples from a basket full of good ones.
__________________________________________
DISCLAIMER: All opinions in this column reflect the views of the author. The author is independent researcher and has no affiliation (nor connection of any kind) to the parties mentioned in the text.
[1] https://ec.europa.eu/info/strategy/priorities-2019-2024/europe-fit-digital-age/digital-markets-act-ensuring-fair-and-open-digital-markets_en
[2] https://ec.europa.eu/competition-policy/sectors/ict/dma_de
[3] https://www.euractiv.com/section/digital/opinion/eu-must-resist-attempts-to-dilute-digital-markets-act/
[4] https://www.nytimes.com/2020/08/13/technology/apple-fortnite-ban.html
[5] https://www.nytimes.com/2020/08/13/technology/apple-fortnite-ban.html
[6] https://www.reuters.com/article/us-apple-epic-games/epic-games-wins-support-from-fortnite-gamers-firms-on-apple-standoff-idUSKCN25A21J
[7] https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/ip_21_2061
[8] https://newsroom.spotify.com/2019-03-13/consumers-and-innovators-win-on-a-level-playing-field/
[9] https://choice.npr.org/index.html?origin=https://www.npr.org/2021/09/10/1036043886/apple-fortnite-epic-games-ruling-explained
[10]See https://storage.courtlistener.com/recap/gov.uscourts.cand.364265/gov.uscourts.cand.364265.812.0_2.pdf
[11] https://twitter.com/timsweeneyepic/status/1436370670166945792
[12] https://www.pcgamesn.com/steam-revenue-cut-tim-sweeney
________________________
To make sure you do not miss out on regular updates from the Kluwer Competition Law Blog, please subscribe here.
Kluwer Competition Law
The 2022 Future Ready Lawyer survey showed that 79% of lawyers are coping with increased volume & complexity of information. Kluwer Competition Law enables you to make more informed decisions, more quickly from every preferred location. Are you, as a competition lawyer, ready for the future?
Learn how Kluwer Competition Law can support you.
Thanks for interesting read, yet is is far from being complete.
This post conveniently omits the main question: why have Eva and Jazz decided to move in and buy property in Appletown in the first place?
Before the move they surely knew that the property prices in Appletown are above those in Anytown next door. They also knew (upfront) that all stores in Appletown carry only a certain selection of goods, which might not be available elsewhere; or if it was available, the pricing might be different. Yet, they decided (freely) to move in and settle in Appletown. Further, after having lived in Appletown for some time they are really free to move elsewhere, selling their house and taking their furniture with them. Really. This is obviously not cost-free, but if they consider that the printer (and other groceries that they would have to buy over their life-time does not justify it) is to cumbersome to get in Appletown and it is much more convenient/cheaper to source in Anytown – they can move on. There is no obligation to live in Appletown.
Did they settle in Appletown because all houses there had the appealing look, and all corners were designed in a special way? Was it because Appletown city council/owner took care to ensure that everything in Appletown really works and matches each other: round corners of the houses are appealing, the Appletown library has a nice collection of books and music which caters to the taste of Appletown citizens. Was it perhaps that half of the family of Eva and Jazz already lived in Appletown, making it easy to meet, organize events and share family photos and music (which is really cumbersome with those living outside)? And half of their friends live there as well, which made the decision to move in a bit easier, despite higher prices for homes and groceries.
Was it perhaps that Appletown offers a different (better?) view of the sea-side, than Anytown? Did it perhaps have a different/better/more appealing selection of other amenities (roads (maps), telecoms networks (messaging)), which made it appealing to live in Appletown rather the somewhere else? Was Appletown more secure than Anytown? Was living in Appletown (perhaps unjustifiably?) perceived as more posh and trendy, and Eva and Jazz just contemplated to broadcast their live-style on a streaming platform, gaining fame and eyeballs, from their peers (and this in itself had a greater value for them that a the cost of printer for their wedding, which they surely consider as a one-time investment, hence justifying the additional costs for Appletown’s property and shopping)? Do you know it? I don’t.
What made them move into Appletown (with all the benefits and drawbacks), rather then somewhere else? The “somewhere else” is not just Anytown next door (let’s not get into collective dominance of the 2 mainstream OSs; yes, I am aware of that, but there is also plenty of other towns to live in, nearby. And collective dominance between Appletown and Anytown (android) would be really far fetched given Airtours).
Another real-life example:
Before committing to their joint fate and moving to Appletown, Jazz met Eva in New York (at a book exhibition). Jazz, wishing to impress Eva, invites her to the best restaurant in town, with harbor view, and one which has earned it’s reputation over the years and has invested in a prime location, in hiring the best chefs and training its staff (for avoidance of doubts: there is only one “best” restaurant in town; there are others, but they are not perceived so good).
Jazz books a place on Friday evening.
Once there, Jazz pulls his mobile and orders pizza via Ub*rEats platform, this will arrive within 10 mins. Next, realizing that a bottle of Champagne in the restaurant costs 3x as much as he has paid for it in local convenience shop, he pulls it out of his backpack. He asks the waiter for glasses, together with glasses for coke which comes as a compliment with pizza, arriving soon.
In the interest of contestability and fairness Eva and Jazz both enjoy their pizza, champagne, complimentary coke, the magnificent sea-side view, as well as discrete selection of live music playing in the background, performed by town’s best artist. Jazz dishes out 40 bucks in total; Eva pays nothing and is invited (two-sided market, after all).
Jazz is slightly puzzled when Eva say “no” on the first date, but still they move to Appletown (thanks to DMA!) few years later. Happy ending.
On a more serious note:
– what made them move to Appletown in the first place? Perhaps they are just fine with the higher price for printers there (in exchange for a different sea-side view which they liked more, for the perception of security, and having their grand-parents within reach). Also, in digital world, competition is always a few clicks away.
Given significant savings, customers will endure few more clicks. If they don’t, it just means they are fine with it. Move on.
– My reading of Epic vs Apple is that the market was defined even more broadly, not just Apple OS vs Android, but rather “all devices on which one can play games” (if true/correct, then finding Apple’s dominance on iOS is really difficult, yet I know to little of the facts/data). Happy to see that clarified;
– Judgment is ambiguous. Can Apple prohibit 3rd party in-app purchases (seemingly: yes), maintaining its walled garden? Or, Apple is not allowed to maintain it, and must allow circumvention by at least one-more-click? Is it really the issue of number of clicks away which sets them apart (unlikely)? Hence, clarity needed.
– on the restaurant example: is the “best restaurant in town” a relevant market on its own? Should it be regulated ex ante? What about such restos charging 3x the cost of food and 5x for wine and water (easily)? Is it excessive? Or do you perhaps pay for sea-side view and atmosphere (how do you price that?)? For not having to cook and clean? Should someone regulate them? Should we allow guests to order food deliveries to restaurants and come with their own bottle? No? Why not? Everything that is illegal offline should also be illegal on-line .…
– just food for thought.
Disclaimer: nothing to declare here. Not involved with/not representing any side. Observing from distance.